Yuri Tarnopolsky
ESSAYS Essay 35. Crowds and Elites,
Bottlenecks and Demons
elite. power. few and many. law of small
numbers. Randall Collins. sociology of philosophers.
society of mind. distribution of wealth. power.
democracy. elections. Pareto. shark fin distribution.
econophysics. sociophysics. sociochemistry. Use Firefox browser or see essays-complete.pdf |
![]() ![]()
Essay 35.
Crowds and Elites, Bottlenecks and Demons From poverty
to its opposite and back, from the beginning to the end:
this Essay continues Essay 31, On Poverty, which
was its true beginning. I believe
that the topic of distribution of wealth and power, as
soon as we start asking simple questions, leads us to
the most general understanding of society, similar to
the understanding of matter and life in terms of
thermodynamics. Moreover, the two understandings can be
just one. Power, money, energy of a physical system,
psychological stress of an individual or society—all
that is actually the measure of the probability of
change, applicable to any natural system. I do not
pretend that I have this kind of understanding, but I
believe that the major categories we need for it are: large
and small, many and few, short
time and long time. The generalized energy of
complex systems can be measured only relatively, but
this should suffice. I don't see any reason why a new
term would be needed instead of the familiar energy. Let us take
molecules of gas and people as comparable models. There
is a radical difference between molecules in bottle and
people in society, in spite of many similarities (both
are dynamic systems). We can see the differences with
the naked eye, but there is also a radical difference
between a very large number of molecules (people) and a
small number of them which is not quite so obvious and
needs some mental tools to see. The
difference is: the large dynamic system tends to come to
the most probable state—it can be equilibrium or steady
state—which makes many other imaginable states not just
extremely improbable, but outright impossible, while a
small system can go through all its imaginable states in
any order. Thus, molecules in a bottle of air cannot
even for a fleeting moment gather in one half of the
bottle. Moreover, they cannot create even a slight
difference in the density of molecules between the
halves. On the
contrary, ten flies in a bottle can all gather in one
half, although not for a long time, unless there is a
speck of food, and ten people in a room not only avoid
homogenous distribution but can (and like to) gather in
groups of two and more, and even all together if there
is a tidbit of news to discuss. This is the
same as to say that small systems do not have history:
they do not distinguish between the very first and all
the subsequent repetitions of the same state. A small group
can be in a moderate number of states. Five people
can answer a single question with YES or NO in 2*2*2*2*2=32 ways:
YES, NO, NO, YES, NO; NO, YES, NO, NO, YES,
NO , etc. The probability of accidental unanimity
is significant: 1/32=0.03125. The probability of a
unanimous answer by a group of 1000 people is negligible
because the number of possible combinations of answers
is astronomical (2¹ººº) and people can
have all kinds of ideas, even very weird ones. And
nevertheless, millions are ready to vote for Donald
Trump because electoral choice is a very small system. There are
very few artificial unrealistic questions that a
thousand people can answer unanimously, unless this
group is artificially selected, heavily brainwashed, or
watched by Big Bad Brother. Examples are: "do you want
to die today? do you want to pay less tax? do you want
to get a million dollars?" A small group, especially
with a leader, can easily work out a single stand on a
practical issue, even if there are internal
disagreements. It is never a problem if there is a
leader with a decisive advantage or the other choice is
ridiculous. A small
group is capable not only of mulling over a wide range
of pros and contras but also of issuing a decision
or answer as if it were one man. A small group works as
a single brain, only much better (a single brain can
work poorly enough). There are reasons to believe that
the power of human minds can be additive and it is
possible to create a better mind by hooking several
individual minds in a certain way. This is how the
theoretical physics of the first half of the twentieth
century was made: in small groups of elite scientists
and their students. Usually, however, human ambitions
produce three opinions for two people. The system
of US elections shows how little the important
decisions are entrusted to the large population (and for
good reasons). Two candidates are often promoted by
small groups in such a way that they are expected to
have close chances and cause a maximal division of
voters, i.e., into halves close in size. The Bush-Gore
elections of 2000 are an example, although the
candidates could hardly be more different. Of
course, any trace of elitism is a deadly flaw for a
candidate's chances. No party
puts forward a hopeless candidate. There are local
referendums, but has anybody ever suggested a national
referendum on "do you want to pay less tax" or "do you
want a million dollars now?" Politics is similar to the
principle of trial lawyers: never ask a question if you
don't know the answer in advance. And yet Election 2016
starts as a true revolution against established order. As the large
number of molecules is governed by the laws of nature,
the large number of people is governed by the laws of
human nature. How different both laws are is a separate
question. Here I am interested in the difference between
the crowd and the elite, the large
and the small, the few and the many. Crowd is a society or
its large segment, i.e., a large number of independent
but interacting members. All scientists form a crowd:
they exchange ideas, knowledge, praise, and criticism. A
crowd of companies interact through business
transactions, lobbying, advertisement, competition, and
partnership. Investors in stock market form a different
crowd: they lose and gain, gambling for a fluctuating
resource. Members of competing crowds interact through
cooperation and struggle. What is important about the
crowd, it is its large size, so that most of its
parameters have a meaningful statistics and the crowd
can be described not through a list of its members and
their properties but through statistical distributions
and parameters. Crowd is an
example of a system. System, however, is a more abstract
concept, Systems can be small, built of dependent parts,
of mostly identical entities, etc. Crowd is a large
human system built of interacting individuals or groups.
All of them are different even if they want to be like
the other guy. A member of
a crowd tries to maximize a certain value, for example,
limelight, wealth, prestige, power, authority, and
influence. The higher the value, the easier to
increase it. At the same time, because the total value
of a crowd in the short run is approximately the same,
the more one member gets, the less the others have. This
is why the higher the value, the more difficult
to increase it, but for different reasons. I will call
the value resource. It is something that can be
transferred, shared, multiplied, or destroyed in the
interactions between the members of the crowd, so that
the total cumulative resource is approximately constant
and changes slowly. Examples
of a catastrophic change of resource: severe drought,
sharp depression, war and embargo, sharp change of oil
prices, stock bubble. It is the
main axiom of classical capitalist economics of Adam
Smith that every human wants to maximize wealth. Kenneth
Galbraith noted that power, too, must to be in the
picture, although it is not a classical economic notion.
According to my observations, the generalization about
the universality of the will to wealth and power does
not seem obvious. There are two main reasons for that. First, what
all people want (with very small exception) is
happiness. It was noted by the ancient Greeks long
before not only capitalism, but even feudalism. It may
take various forms, including stability, attention of
others, altruistic service, pursuing a goal, leisure,
even sloth. The desire of wealth and power belongs to
independent properties of individuals. The intensity of
my desire for wealth and power is by no means influenced
by other people's desires and vice versa. The fact is
that people vary very widely in what they want and how
much they want it. For immigrants from poor or
devastated by war countries the desires may be limited
by stability and peace, which are not economic values at
all. Many who go to the academe do so for the sake of
stability, among other reasons. Some others do it for
the love of the profession. Some people need respect and
praise as much as others need wealth and power and one
set does not guarantee the other. Moreover,
even from the theoretical standpoint, in a statistical
crowd, any independent property must be distributed more
or less symmetrically along a bell curve, with a few
having a high value of this property (height, strength,
ambition, drive for wealth, drive for power,
imagination, etc.). Whether we are tall or short, it has
no influence whatsoever on the height of other unrelated
to us people. Whether we are rich or poor, it has an
influence on the well-being of other people, if we
assume that the total amount of wealth is approximately
constant. I use the vague but popular term "bell curve" because it is the general shape of distribution that matters most, regardless of its mathematical form. There are two extreme cases: symmetrical (bell curve) and strongly shifted (shark fin) distributions, compared in Figure 1. ![]() The shark fin shape appears when the members of the crowd depend on each other in their personal values, which is possible in the case of competition for a resource.
Figure 1. Bell curve and shark
fin distributions Elite is a smaller
part of the crowd, with the highest cumulative amount of
the resource. Elite represents the higher
(right) end of the shark fin distribution (see Essay
31. On Poverty). The high (right) wing of the bell
curve is also an elite, it may be the highest IQ
intellectual elite, but neither political nor the
financial one because people do not depend on other
unrelated people in their IQ and there is no limit on
total IQ. Physical strength, height, IQ, and inborn
melancholy are intensive values while wealth and power
are extensive values. By elite I mean here only the
"extensive" elite. Energy is a measure of
the ability of a system to change. High energy means
instability, i.e., high probability of change.
Life—biological or social—happens only in open systems
where a certain order can be maintained only by a supply
of physical energy. Energy (known in physics as free
energy, see Essay 7, On the Smell of Money)
has two components: physical energy and internal order. The difference
between the two tells how much work could be done by
this energy. Social
synonyms of energy, however, are a very poorly
researched subject. Social thermodynamics (part of it is
emerging as econophysics and sociophysics), together
with social psychology and sociology, might contribute
to our understanding of social and individual energy.
The problem with physics, however, is that it is not
accustomed to dealing with structures of high and
irreducible complexity which cannot be shrunk to a few
equations. This might be the subject of sociochemistry,
however. To
illustrate the problems with energy, here are some
examples of arising questions: 1. What
happens during the transfer of knowledge? A scientist of
a lower rank may increase both the status of a higher
rank scientist who uses the knowledge of the former, and
his/her own status. What is lost? What is preserved? GUESS:
No loss. Knowledge is growing and is very far from being
a conservative resource. A steady state is theoretically
possible, at least, imaginable. The prestige of the low
rank scientist slowly accumulates, while the high rank
scientist who refers to the other creates a possible
competitor. 2. Money in
a crowd can be regarded as energy (Essay 31,
appendix). Is a transferred quantity of money really
preserved or part of it is dissipated? Or the transfer
creates value, as in a loan or investment? GUESS:
The entire modern economic system is a device to
dissipate the energy of mineral and other fuel.
While the fuel lasts, economy is still growing and money
is being created at transactions. A steady state is
possible, but it is not in sight, yet. 3. What is
the difference between voluntary competition (or
exchange of knowledge), and forced one, as in a chess
championship where a master has to prove his title? GUESS:
Fame, like in cases of champion status or beauty crown,
is the most conservative resource. If it still expands,
it is because advertisement and media industries need
stars as raw material for growth. A star is a vehicle
for money-making. Exchange of fame is still unhindered.
Exchange of knowledge is one of the most restricted
transactions in industry and increasingly in academia
because of patent law. Entropy is a measure of
disorder in the crowd: the higher entropy, the lower
order, the higher chaos. Energy can be used to increase
order, which is possible in natural or man-made machines
such as organisms and pop stars. Order means that there
are rules of interaction and some changes are facing
strong opposition, while others are alleviated. Temperature is the price of
a unit of energy in terms of order it can create.
In other words, it is the conversion rate between energy
and order. A different view—compatible with the first
one—is that the temperature of the crowd is the average
value of the resource. Example: gold fever. The factor
of an underestimated importance is time. History
consists of events and processes in time. Bottleneck
is the slowest stage of a multistage process. It is also
known as the weakest link: the location of most
probable change. They both are limiting factors.
Demon is part of the
system that increases the order in spite of the general
tendency to disorder. Demon can work very efficiently if
it sits at the bottleneck. Bureaucracy, government, and
corruption create bottlenecks and assign demons to
collect toll for a passage. Government agencies are
demons, not in any derogatory sense, but... mafia
is also a demon. See APPENDIX
2. Star is the winner in
contest for attention and recognition. Everything linked
to a star is supposed to attract attention, too. The
star is a temporary member of star elite, which is very
fluid. The star for a snickers company is like gold rush
for a spade trader. What is
political power, then? Power in society is a
very tricky phenomenon. It is easy to tell what it is
not: it is not the ability to maintain order, i.e., keep
entropy low by using energy, usually, in monetary form.
Same low entropy corresponds to different arrangements
of society. Equal powers can be used to maintain
incompatible orders. Loose autocracy and inefficient
democracy may keep the same entropy of society. A person
who has great corporate power may be powerless in his
own family. Power is
a social mechanism of applying
energy (in the form of money, of course) for creating a
particular order against another power that applies
energy for creating a different order. Political power
is not just money or any other resource. Like the power
station, transformer, power line, local transformer, and
electrical outlets in a neighborhood, or like the
engine, transmission, steering, and wheels of a
car, power is a device that performs a certain
function and maintains a certain structure of order by
consuming energy, dissipating part of it, and
transforming the rest into order. Social power is never
universal, neither it is abstract. This is why
political power can be bought. It is a kind of a Thing:
a machine, an organization, and even an organism, like
horses in agriculture or elephants in the army of
Hannibal. The one who buys a power device must also buy
fuel every day. Power feeds on money. Power is a
mechanism, an engine: it needs to be designed, built,
painted in cheerful colors, oiled, maintained, served by
specialists, supplied with energy, and used. This is why
not just government or a big corporation can have power.
In capitalist democracy, everybody who has money or can
raise funds can buy components and build a mechanism of
power, possibly, as a little corg (Essay 33, The Corg).
This is exactly why the corg is possible: it is a gadget
manufacturing a certain increment of a general political
order. For the elephants of power, voluntary
contributions are a very inefficient way to graze. Corgs of a
very limited scope are already built into large
corporations, as Kenneth Galbraith noted, but what I
personally see is the evolutionary divergence of the
corporate host and its internal symbiont. The loose
anti-globalization movement and global terrorism are
both examples of yet imperfect corgs that are free of
material production. They have a corporate nature and
are completely focused on social and political change.
Note that in modern world destruction is the cheapest
activity: it goes on even if you don't move a finger
(See Essay 34, On Loss). The Russian
Bolsheviks, who built the party machine, overturned the
social order in 1917, and kept refining the new order,
were the evolutionary predecessors of modern corgs.
Interestingly, the Bolsheviks created also a giant
national manufacturing conglomerate, but destroyed all
its competitors up to the last man. The external
competitors, however, toppled the classical
black-leather-jacket Bolshevik in the 60's. Kenneth
Galbraith believes in the spirit of team work and
genuine dedication and pride of the employees of a large
corporation. I am less idealistic, and although team
enthusiasm cannot be denied, it is the material reward
(or fear of punishment, as in Soviet Russia) that keeps
it burning. The Bolsheviks maintained the team
enthusiasm by telling the people that they worked if not
for themselves then for their children who would be in
worker's paradise. Remarkably, the terrorists, too,
promise paradise, as well as justice on earth. Whatever
subject of these Essays we touch upon, it points to
enormous amount of available literature. Art, entropy,
poverty, energy, liberalism, competition, Technos…
thousands of books, papers, and web pages. Does it make
sense to squeeze a droplet out of each giant fruit of
knowledge, all the more, if this droplet can evaporate
right before our eyes? It is
exactly the tiny size of the droplet that makes sense.
Only a small volume of knowledge, like an ancient saying
or a modern aphorism, can be applied to large multitude
of situations. I do not
believe in utilitarian benefits of general knowledge,
small in volume, portable, and as applicable to any
problem as a lock-pick. I believe in the benefits of
detailed, profound, and professional knowledge, which
cannot be found in one person and is distributed among
specialists. My Essays are not a source of this kind of
professional knowledge. It is a source of some questions
and answers. The answers can be disputed and changed for
better ones: they are just seeds of professional
answers. The questions point to the places where to
plant them. The Essays belong neither to sciences, nor
to humanities, but, as I hope, to a narrow tidal strip
between them where the waves of humanities wet the dry
sand of sciences, rolling back and forth. As I believe
in art, I believe in esthetic qualities of general
knowledge. If poetry
and art have any function, it is to obscure the essence
of human nature, to complicate and embellish it
(sometimes with dirt), and to turn into mystery. This is
what poet does in the most intimate poetry. Art makes
life look more complex than life really is. If one asked
why the modern art makes an opposite impression, I would
say that modern art is not about life: it is about art.
Similarly, abstract knowledge, which is concerned with
the most general properties of the world, is not about
the world: it is about knowledge. There is even a
disturbing similarity between modern art and abstract
knowledge: they both are reducible to a small number of
principles and they both dehumanize our view of the
world by rejecting its anthropocentric design. NOTE (2016). To be
objective, whatever that means, science should not
depend on properties of humans . Individual humans are
not present in equations, other than in their
authorship. But
science is free to ask any question. The question
on my mind is: then how can the science (real science)
of human matters be possible? The answer is: by using
patterns instead of equations. Looking back
at my life, I see that nothing, except my family,
enriched my life as much as my interest in understanding
the world around me, whether it was the science of
chemistry, which was the source of my income, or
completely useless knowledge about things with no
relation to my life, like the cuneiform dream books of
ancient Babylonians. Do I
understand what I am writing about? The process
of understanding is like listening to music or reading a
novel: it captures my attention and gives a kind of
satisfaction which no physical pleasure can give. Like
art, it takes me to a different world. Probably, it is
not such a big paradox because knowledge consists of
ideas, and ideas are certainly nothing we can feel with
our senses. Understanding is the most refined of all
human pleasures: you acquire the ability to touch and
feel ideas as if they were pebbles on the beach. It does
not last, and if you once enjoyed understanding, you
want it again and again. Even wrong understanding is a
treasure: it can be exchanged for a better one. The ancient
advice "know thyself," which Socrates heard from the
Oracle of Delphi, does not seem as enlightening as "know
the nature of things." While Thales of Miletus said that
to "understand thyself" is extremely difficult, Albert
Einstein was optimistic about understanding the world.
"The most incomprehensible thing about our universe is
that it is comprehensible" is ascribed to him, although
I was unable to find the reference. I see the
subject differently: it is extremely hard to understand
the world, but easy to understand myself, even if it is
difficult to accept the unflattering self-understanding.
This is why self-knowledge is discouraging while
exploration of the world is a source of unending joy. As
soon as we know ourselves, life ends because nothing can
add to it. We lose the mystery of our existence and
become predictable, though unreliable, cogs in the
mechanism of the world, even if we do not know how the
mechanism works. The world is
enormous in size and complexity. Why can we understand
it? There are several reasons, but all of them have the
same pattern: we represent a large number of
objects by a small number of ideas. As Henry
Poincare said, mathematics names many things with one
name, and the same is true about physics and any
science. We operate
with ideas, and ideas, like modeling clay, fuse together
into a small number of large pieces which are also
ideas. Unlike clay, however, all ideas, regardless of
generality, have the same size and weight because they
are immaterial. This is what makes them so different
from the pebbles: one cannot find two identical material
objects, unless they are stamped out by some machine,
which is also a realization of some idea. NOTE: Having said that, I
suddenly realize the origin of the idea of equality: it
regards human beings as ideas. Or, to put it differently,
it is an idealized picture of the real world.
There is an
intellectual space, which can be compared with an area
of land populated by packs of sophisticated
animals who, believe it or not, graze mostly on grass,
and only occasionally kill and eat devour each other.
The packs (sounds more appropriate than "herds") have a
certain hierarchy, with dominant males as leaders. My
biological interpretation of Collins' ideas is strongly
influenced by his own eloquent imagery: Imagine a large number of
people spread out across an open plain—something like a
landscape by Salvador Dali or Giorgio de Chirico. Each
one is shouting, “Listen to me!” This is the
intellectual attention space (p. 38). [See APPENDIX 2] I substitute animals for people in
order to emphasize the competitive and compulsive nature
of interaction. There is a
certain limit of density of intellectual animals on
feeding grounds. If it is exceeded, the extra males have
to leave the pack. Conversely, if the number of animals
too low, they cannot breed. Thus, Collins establishes
the number of coexisting and competing intellectual
families (or packs; schools, to be exact) in the area as
three to six. This is his law of small numbers, which
can be interpreted as the power of an elite. Collins'
picture is much larger and richer than that: he
describes the networks of intellectual
relationships between different schools and rituals of
the interaction between individuals. I would say that an
intellectual needs to mate with other intellectuals, and
there are as many sexes as there are intellectuals. In
the fight for a mate, instead of joining the leader and
waiting for an opportunity, one might either become
hostile to other seekers. One projection of the entire
multidimensional picture gives a shadowy impression of
biological struggle for existence on a limited resource.
Naturally, it leads to evolution. This seems
to be a very realistic picture for philosophy and
humanities in general, where fashion plays a certain
role, limiting the number of "designers," but natural
sciences avoid overpopulation by splitting and
self-fragmenting into specialized area, as it happened
with chemistry, sociology, and anything else.
Conflicting "schools" is a rare phenomenon in modern
experimental sciences but can be seen at the level of
hypotheses. Thus, the area of biological evolution,
which cannot be observed in all detail and can be
subjected only to a very limited experiment, consists of
schools of thoughts, and even creationists try to be
one. The
sociology of philosophers along Randall Collins seems to
differ little from the sociology of politicians. Modern
natural sciences, in an extraordinary fashion, are
moving closer and closer to politics and philosophy, at
least in America, because science today is a competition
for limited resources of money and attention. The
scientists, too, attract money either by demonstrating
their traditionalism and loyalty to proven leaders, or
by splitting off new branches and brandishing the
novelty and revolutionary promises of their research. The result
of the fragmentation of science is that not only most
scientists lose the general view of the world, but they
lose any interest in such a view. All they want is to
breed, compete for dominance, and stop slightly above
their level of incompetence, and this is perfectly
normal today. Pareto's
distribution (Essay 31, On
Poverty) applies to
production of knowledge as much as it applies to
production of wealth: a few leading intellectuals
(dominant "males;" some of them females) produce a vast
majority of publications—a well-researched fact . It is
among a few leading thinkers that the larger picture of
the world can be found, and Ilya Prigogine, Ulf
Grenander, Randall Collins, Edward O. Wilson, and,
probably, Neill Ferguson are those I would think about
among my contemporaries. I believe
there are two reasons why the larger world can be
understood: 1. Because it can
be split into small areas which can be seen in
all details. Their modest complexity is quite easily
manageable by postgraduates because standard elements
and relations between them are identified in larger
areas. The interests of most intellectuals, whose
function is teaching and generation of published ideas,
are limited by a small list of topics, as anybody can
see in the listings of department faculties. 2. Because only a
small volume of knowledge applies to all its
small areas. Hierarchy of intellectuals, leaders,
knowledge, wealth, and power, as well as hierarchy of
abstract principles descending down the scale toward the
ground is the reality. The principles, however, range
from completely untestable, as religion and philosophy
(all religions and philosophies are equally true and
false) to those experimentally testable before the jury
of peers. Therefore,
an intellectual needs a small volume of general abstract
knowledge applied to a small area of research. Very
general and abstract principles, however, are difficult
to interpret. We can see big disputes—burnt out as well
as ongoing—about such fundamental things as information,
entropy, life, and evolution. My thesis in
this Essay is the universal importance of the opposition
between large and small. It is
definitely inspired by the Randall Collins' law of small
numbers Not only the volume of all knowledge is large
and that of most important general principles is small,
but also the power of small number of people vastly
surpasses the power of large masses. Power, knowledge,
and wealth are productive only when they are
concentrated. This is why this world can be not only
understood but also managed by creating a hierarchy of
concentration with either elite or a single sovereign at
the top. But what
about the will of the people and democracy? To
express and execute their will, the people elect the
government. What self-respecting freedom-loving people
would form a such a giant mechanism for the function
that could be performed by a small elite? Da capo
al fine. hat is
democracy, then? It legitimizes the fight for dominant
position. It establishes the Pareto distribution of
wealth and influence. It typically (with some
exceptions) gives people as much power as they have
wealth. Do the people decide? No. A crowd cannot decide
anything because decisions can be made only in small
groups. A crowd can select between presented options and
every vote is already largely ordered by the
presentation of options and has only a limited random
component in it. "It is not that anything's wrong with
it" (Seinfeld). It is natural. But it is not what many
people think: it is not about equality. Absolute
equality is absolute zero of social temperature. Fine. APPENDIX: 1.
Sociophysics. Arnopoulos, P.
(1993). Sociophysics: A General Theory of Natural
and Cultural Systems (Nova Science Publishers) I could
not find it in the libraries and, unfortunately, it
costs over $100. I am not a good example to illustrate
the theories of Adam Smith. 2.
Pandemonium. Metaphorically we can think of a set of workers, all
looking at the same blackboard: each is able to read
everything that is on it, and to judge when he has
something worthwhile to add to it. This conception is just
that of Selfridge Pandemonium
([Oliver] Selfridge,
1959): a set of demons, each independently looking at the
total situation and shrieking in proportion to what they
see that fits their natures (Allen Newell, 1962). Also, on
Pandemonium and other topics: Mark Humphrys'
site. I see in it a
general concept of sociology of mind, from which I
conclude that the society of philosophers is,
actually, a collective mind, working as the single mind
in Artificial Intelligence (AI). A good
recent book on AI: Stan Franklin, Artificial Minds,
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1995. That
one I bought and did not regret.
3.
Statistics as the study of crowds There
are objects and there are their measurable properties.
Any such property is ordered: for any
two values we can say which is larger. Time, energy,
position, and other physical variables are naturally
ordered: one variable is larger than other. So are IQ,
wealth, creative productivity, sports achievements, etc.
Physics expresses the dependence of one variable on
another in the form of mathematical function. Some
human properties, for example, ethical ones, cannot be
exactly measured, but there are other ways, see Essay
13, On Numbers. Objects cannot be
ordered. All we can say about them is that one is not
the other. People, animals, plants, seeds, words,
events, molecules, etc., and, actually all objects,
not their properties, do not have numbers on their
backs. If they have, they can be numbered in any order:
the number is just a name tag, as on the back of a
football layer. This is what crowd is by definition.
Mathematics cannot arrange a crowd in line, unless
by some property. Statistics looks at their
measurable properties per se and
tries to find out how a property is distributed over the
crowd of objects. It analyzes the connection
between the value of a property and the number of
members of the crowd that have it. Clearly, statistics
cannot say anything about a particular objects, except
in terms of probabilities. One needs very special skills
to use the fruits of such apparently idle occupation,
but the results could be powerful. Still, using
probability theory, born from the card games, for
personal goals may be as much a winning as a losing
business. Mathematics of crowds works better for crowds
themselves.
|
Page
created:
2002
Revised:
2016 Essays 1 to 56 : http://spirospero.net/essays-complete.pdf Essays 57 to 60: http://spirospero.net/LAST_ESSAYS.pdf Essay 60: http://spirospero.net/artandnexistence.pdf |